BP Comment Quick Links
December 28, 2015 Tools of IgnoranceBehavioral Economics and the Rise of the Player Opt-Out“The logic of the opt-out clauses for the club escapes me.” —Commissioner Rob Manfred Nothing gets the baseball internet writer hot like a newly popularized contract structure. Rob Neyer has weighed in on the potential benefit to team of a player opt-out, and Dave Cameron* has weighed in on how these cannot be seen as anything but additional costs. Neyer’s point is that giving a player an opt-out is often preferable to giving a player more money. Cameron’s point is that giving a player an opt-out is less preferable than not giving a player an opt-out. Both points are correct. Like most things, if we change the perspective, then we can look at anything as a positive or a negative. More simply, everything is better than a worse scenario and everything is worse than a better scenario. So why the need for another article? Because unaddressed remains the most curious question about the player option: Why has it become so popular? Put differently, what benefit does the structure provide for each side as an alternative (in most mega-deals) to just agreeing on more money? We will take a look at what is in it for both parties and see what we can find. Going back to Neyer’s assertion—that teams prefer giving such an option to giving more money—well, that comes with a big ol’ “it depends.” My guess is that teams perform some sort of analysis and put a value on offering a player option for each year of the contract (something similar to what was done by Eno Sarris, probably including the frictional costs mentioned by FanGraphs commenter Josh), and then negotiate with that cost in mind. For example, if a team values an opt-out for a specific player at year three of a six-year contract at $12 million, they would be indifferent to the choice between a six-year, $132 million contract with no opt-out and a six-year, $120 million contract with a player opt-out after year three. All this is to say that teams would prefer giving a player option to giving more money to a point. So, either contracts with player options are falling more and more on the “more favorable than paying more” side of this cost-benefit analysis, or players value the opt-out more than teams do. First, we'll take a look at this from the players’ perspective. Optimism
Additionally, we imagine the best from ourselves. We are going to exercise more, eat healthier, be better listeners, be more available friends and partners, wake up earlier, get more sleep, save more money, spend more time doing what we love, bring lunch more, eat out less, clip our big-toenails more frequently, floss, save more money, withdraw less cash from out of network ATMs, etc. Then the alarm goes off and we hit snooze. Then we walk into work and Sharon from operations finance brings in those unbelievably delicious Danishes from the bakery by wherever she lives and we eat 75 percent of our daily calories before lunch starts.
Combine these ways that we are overly optimistic about the future, and it becomes unsurprising when when a 29-year-old baseball player agrees to sign for $15 million less in order to potentially cash in on another payday at age 32. If he continues to perform as forecasted and if money continues to flow into the game, then his $15 million will most likely pay off fivefold, and we love betting on ourselves. One only needs to look at the divorce rate, or the failure rate for startups. Additionally, the more successful we are (such as being good enough at baseball to be the recipient of $100 million-plus contract) the more ammunition our brains have to convince ourselves that the future holds less risk than it really does. Intertemporal Choice
By this logic, players might want to take more money and pass on the opt-out for smaller contracts (instead of potentially deferring a couple million dollars), while preferring to take less money with the opt-out for larger contracts (as to not potentially defer tens of millions of dollars or more). Mental Accounting Most of us have never been in the position to decide between $170 million over six years and $150 million over six years with opt-outs at years three and five, but we can certainly imagine the benefits (beyond the potential financial upside) that would make the latter more appealing. What if ownership or management changes for the worse? What if I do not love the area and want to play somewhere else? Moreover, if the player values non-monetary factors while the teams only value monetary factors, then this is something we would expect given how negotiation works. Parties generally prefer to concede those things they prioritize lower, in order to get more of what they prioritize highly. Given the above, there appear to be plenty of reasons why players might be valuing player options more than they did before and more than teams do, particularly for large contracts. Given the influx of money into the game and given the increased sophistication of today’s front offices, these reasons might be all that are needed for an increase in the popularity of player options. There might be, though, reasons that the player option is more of a benefit to the teams as well (which will be covered more briefly).
Ultimately, the player option, like any other contract structure, has a value (positive or negative) to the player and to the team, just as an extra year or an extra dollar does. Consequently, the rise of the player option is maybe not as unexplainable as Commissioner Manfred thinks. If the assumption is that teams are simply offering $150 million with an opt-out and $150 million without an opt-out, then yes, of course, the opt-out makes no sense. But if we assume that the opt-out comes with less money than would otherwise be offered (and this is a more reasonable assumption), then we cannot know the actual costs of the player options being agreed to in these contracts. Based on the above, though, it appears that the player option might actually be more of boon to teams than we think. *It should also be noted that Cameron has written pretty exhaustively and excellently about the subject—taking a look at it from multiple angles—looking at many of the different costs and benefits associated with the structure.
Jeff Quinton is an author of Baseball Prospectus. Follow @jjq01
11 comments have been left for this article.
|
From a team's perspective, I haven't heard anyone consider either opportunity cost or the greater fool's theory.
Contracts have historically reduced AAV in exchange for more years which is one reason why the back end typically looks bad.
If Heyward opts out, the Cubs will have acquired presumably his three prime years for 3/78 (inc bonus payouts). If it was just a three year deal it would be universally lauded. The Cubs would benefit from ~$10MM in excess value per year if we assume he continues to put up something near 5 wins a season. If he opts out you can assume the Cubs are losing out on future excess, but given contract structures front-load value realization then the Cubs forsake the opportunity to generate 40% returns (e.g. 36MM on Heyward's 26MM AAV), presumably to earn smaller returns. The team has to assume they can continue to structure contracts similarly in the future in order to reappropriate the Heyward dollars to the next player to replace him.
You look at the the team's who have provided these opt-outs and they are the more forward thinking ones. The argument that a player opting out is always bad for the team assumes perfect information about the future. In reality all it takes is 1 person out of 31 (i.e. player, agent or 29 owners) believing there's more value to be had. If I'm Brian Sabean or Theo Epstein I look around at the inflation rate and the absurd contracts that have been offered and believe that even in the case of injury there will be someone dumber than I willing to tack on more money to the contract.
These owners are chasing something that doesn't have a price. "Wasting" an extra 10, 20, 100MM dollars is irrelevant if it brings home the pennant (e.g. Ilitch, Moreno). And even then the overpay isn't absurd. If the owner believes that one player is the key piece then it's justifiable. Economically, that overpay nets out with the future revenue increases a WS brings.
Option holders should always find more value in the option than those on the other side of the table. But they've prepaid for it as you've mentioned and they are not guaranteed to make a good decision. For Manfred and Cameron to universally decry options seems more dogmatic than logical.
Yes, the forward thinking Yankees gave opt-outs to CC and ARod, then turned around and dumped a greater amount of money on them upon their opting out. Oops.
A place that shall not be named took an early look at opt out results. This early in the opt-out game (I dunno, say 2nd inning?) the players have a pretty nice lead.
If Heyward opts out, the Cubs clear a 40% profit.
Of course they lose him for the next 5 years. But are they making 40% on the next 5 years? Probably not.
So what can they do with that money? Can they give Harper the same deal structure, clear 40% on him, and see him leave in 3 years?